пятница, 19 августа 2022 г.

The Value Proposition Canvas by Peter J Thomson

 




A value proposition canvas includes elements from behavioural psychology and design thinking.


A value proposition is the place where your company’s product intersects with your customer’s desires. It’s the magic fit between what you make and why people buy it. Your value proposition is the crunch point between business strategy and brand strategy.

When you’re starting a new project, or a new company, you need practical tools to help you focus on executing things faster and better. Good strategy tools exist only to help you focus on getting the right things done. The value proposition canvas is a fairly simple tool that quickly gets you to the ‘minimum viable clarity’ required to start building and testing a product or service.

A value proposition sits at the pivot point of an entire business model. Mapping the business model of a new product or service is one of the most important parts of building an overall business strategy. Strategy frameworks have traditionally been the domain of MBAs and consultants but they are so important that these days the tools have been democratised for use by entrepreneurs, designers and technical teams.

Business model canvas

The Business Model Canvas is a toolkit from 2009 that drew on Michael Porter’s value chain maps and Peter Drucker’s theories of the firm (among other sources). The Business Model Canvas is a chart that maps the key things that a business needs to get right to be successful.



The Business Model Canvas condenses the main elements of a business strategy into a single page.

The Business Model Canvas has become the preferred tool for modern startups to use when rapidly testing a new business idea. It’s an attractive tool because it condenses years of business school and management consulting practise into a single page (with some straight-forward questions for each section). – This is either a good or a bad thing depending on how much you love management jargon.

Any strategy tool is only really as good as the facilitator or team who are using it. Each tool carries hidden biases and assumptions. So choosing a good tool is important. Strategy tools are great ways of providing structure to a conversation and allowing people outside of the pure strategy professions to think about whether they are doing the right things at the right time, in the right order.

Having used it in several client workshops, my issue with the traditional  Business Model Canvas used to be that it didn’t do enough to encourage empathy with customers and to force the business to be accountable for how they communicated with their audience. In short, it didn’t place enough emphasis on the company’s value proposition.

A “value proposition canvas” is a chart that maps the key things that make up your product and why people buy it. There are many different value proposition canvases. Some are proprietary, some are open source and some are creative commons. Any canvas that helps you understand your customer, your offer and how the two fit together will help you clarify your value proposition.

Alex Osterwalder’s value proposition canvas

In 2012, Alex Osterwalder and his team released their Value Proposition Designer. Their version of the value proposition canvas is copyright and can only be used with credit to www.businessmodelgeneration.com. The Value Proposition Designer includes several bits of thinking from the Lean Startup movement such as “jobs to be done” and “customer pains”. It’s a good tool, but it’s not perfect.


The Value Proposition Designer is copyright by Alex Osterwalder and team. For details see www.businessmodelgeneration.com

The Business Model Generation team renamed their 2012 Value Proposition Designer as a value proposition canvas and published an excellent book in 2014 on the topic called Value Proposition Design. My critique of the Osterwalder (et al.) version of the value proposition canvas is that:

  • The product proposition side isn’t grounded enough in marketing, branding and persuasion techniques. It doesn’t guide the user towards creative thinking and honest self-evaluation.
  • The customer side isn’t grounded enough in behavioural psychology or customer behaviour research. It doesn’t guide the user into deep empathy for their customers or draw out enough new insights.

The psychology of why people buy things

I (like many brand strategists and advertising planners) often find myself standing in a supermarket transfixed, watching other people shop. I could literally stand for hours observing the range of human experience and emotions that go into making even the most seemingly banal shopping decisions. So many different parts of a person’s brain are engaged when they make even the smallest buying decision.

If you’ve ever eaten a doughnut while on a diet then you know that not all human decision making is fully rational. – But even if purchasing behaviour is irrational, it’s still predictable. That’s why I’ve drawn from behavioural economics and choice psychology to rebuild my own take on a value proposition canvas. Modelling human behaviour and decision making is a rich and diverse field of study.  You can read more about how people make decisions and why they do what they do in books such as Nudge, Predictably Irrational, and Thinking Fast And Slow. Personally, I’ve drawn my models for the canvas mainly from the fields of cognitive psychology and behavioural economics.


A new value proposition canvas template

I’ve created a canvas to guide startups into examining the human experience of their customers. This canvas contains questions and sections that manoeuvre users of the canvas into thinking through the end-customer experience.


Each section of the improved canvas includes questions to ask when filling in the chart.

The new product section of the canvas uses the widely accepted marketing syntax of features and benefits with the addition of a box for “experience” (taking from the fields of design thinking and UX architecture). The product understanding section includes:

  • Features – A feature is a factual description of how your product works. The features are the functioning attributes of your product. The features also provide the ‘reasons to believe’. Many FMCG marketers deride the importance of features because features are no longer a point of difference in most FMCG marketing. But for technology products and innovative new services the features on offer can still be an important part of your value proposition.
  • Benefits – A benefit is what your product does for the customer. The benefits are the ways that the features make your customer’s life easier by increasing pleasure or decreasing pain. The benefits of your product are the really core of your value proposition. The best way to list out the benefits of your product on the canvas is to imagine all the ways that your product makes your customer’s life better.
  • Experience – The product experience is the way that owning your product makes the customer feel. It’s the sum total of the combined features and benefits. Product experience is different to features and benefits because it’s more about the emotional reasons why people buy your product and what it means for them in their own lives. The product experience is the kernel that will help identify the market positioning and brand essence that is usually built out of the value proposition.

The customer section draws on nuero-lingusitic programming and psychology research into motivation and choice architecture. It focuses less on “pains” and “gains” because people can be motivated by both pains and gains in different ways. The customer empathy sections include:

  • Wants – The emotional drivers of decision making are things that we want to be, do or have. Our wants are usually conscious (but aspirational) thoughts about how we’d like to improve our lives. They sometimes seem like daydreams but they can be powerful motivators of action. The wants speak more to the pull of our hearts and our emotions. I may need a car to get from A to B, but I want a BMW.
  • Needs – The customer’s needs are the rational things that the customer needs to get done. Interestingly, needs are not always conscious. Customers can have needs that they may not know about yet. Designers call these “latent needs“. The best example is that none of us knew that we needed a portable music player until we saw an iPod for the first time (we also then suddenly wanted an iPod rather than any other perfectly good music player). The needs speak more to the pull of our heads and rational motivations.
  • Fears – The dark side of making a decision is that it often carries a fear of giving up optionality. Fear of making a mistake, fear of missing out, fear of loss and dozens of other related fears. Fears can be a strong driver of purchasing behaviour and can be the hidden source of wants and needs. Customer fears are often the secret reason that no one is buying your widget. For any product there is a secret “pain of switching“. Even if your product is better than the competition, it might not be a big enough improvement to overcome the inertia of the status quo.
  • Substitutes – Some companies claim that they have no direct competitors. The substitutes on the canvas aren’t just the obvious competitors, instead look for the existing behaviours and coping mechanisms. This is on the canvas because it shocks us into remembering that our customers are real people with daily lives who have made it this far in life without our product. No matter how much better your product is than the competition, if it isn’t better than the existing solutions then you don’t have a real-world value proposition.

A key finding from the process of mapping a value proposition is often “we don’t have enough information to answer this section”. That is a perfect moment to adopt a lean startup approach and to get out of the building to ask existing customers and potential customers about their wants, needs and fears. A value proposition canvas can be a great place to begin the process of identifying and validating your assumptions.


Examples of a value proposition canvas

Mapping a company’s value proposition is a great shared exercise for a cross-functional management team. It gets people from outside the marketing team to contribute to marketing insights without having to admit that what they are doing is “marketing” (because marketing can be a loaded term for some professions).

Startup accelerator: Uncovering new value in an existing feature

The Innovation Warehouse is an angel investing syndicate with a co-working space for the member investors and their portfolio of startups. Building a value proposition canvas helped them to identify that a key need for the startups that they want to serve is a quiet and productive space.


The Innovation Warehouse value proposition was adjusted to highlight productivity.

The productive environment was already a feature of the existing space but wasn’t being promoted in the existing marketing materials. It was a simple matter to add the feature into the collateral to address the customer need more clearly in their marketing.

https://bit.ly/3T3y263

Module 1: Preferences and Indifference Curves

 

“Fill ‘Er Up” by derekbruff is licensed under CC BY-NC 2.0


The Policy Question: Is a Tax Credit on Hybrid Car Purchases the Government’s Best Choice to Reduce Fuel Consumption and Carbon Emissions?

The U.S. government, concerned about the dependence on imported foreign oil and the release of carbon into the atmosphere, has enacted policies where consumers can receive substantial tax credits toward the purchase of certain models of all-electric and hybrid cars.

This credit may seem like a good policy choice but it is a costly one, it takes away resources that could be spent on other government policies, and it is not the only approach to decreasing carbon emissions and dependency on fossil fuels.   So how do we decide which policy is best?

Suppose that this tax credit is wildly successful and doubles the average fuel economy of all cars on U.S. roads (this is clearly not realistic but useful for our subsequent discussions).  What do you think would happen to the fuel consumption of all U.S. motorists?  Should the government expect fuel consumption and carbon emissions of U.S. cars to decrease by half in response?

The answers to these questions are critical when choosing among the policy alternatives.   In other words, is offering a subsidy to consumers the most effective way to meet the policy goals of decreased dependency on foreign oil and carbon emissions? Are there more efficient—that is, less expensive–ways to achieve these goals?   The ability to predict with some accuracy the response of consumers to this policy is vital to determining the merits of the policy before millions of federal dollars are spent.

Consumption decisions, such as how much automobile fuel to consume, come fundamentally frompreferences – our likes and dislikes.  Human decision making, driven by our preferences, is at the core of economic theory. Since we can’t consume everything our hearts desire, we have to make choices and those choices are based on our preferences.   Choosing based on likes and dislikes does not mean that we are selfish–our preferences may include charitable giving and the happiness of others.

In this module, we will study preferences in economics.

1.1   Fundamental Assumptions about Individual Preferences

Learning Objective 1.1: List and explain the three fundamental assumptions about preferences.

1.2   Graphing Preferences with Indifference Curves

Learning Objective 1.2: Define and draw an indifference curve.

1.3 Properties of Indifference Curves

Learning Objective 1.3: Relate the properties of indifference curves to assumptions about preference

1.4 Marginal Rate of Substitution

Learning Objective 1.4: Define marginal rate of substitution.

1.5 Perfect Complements and Perfect Substitutes

Learning Objective 1.5: Use indifference curves to illustrate perfect complements and perfect substitutes.

1.6 Policy Example: The Hybrid Car Tax Credit and Consumer Preference

Learning Objective 1.6: Apply indifference curves to the policy of a hybrid car tax credit.

1.1 Fundamental Assumptions about Individual Preferences

Learning Objective 1.1: List and explain the three fundamental assumptions about preferences.

To build a model that can predict choices when variables change, we need to make some assumptions about the preferences that drive consumer choices.

Economics makes three assumptions about preferences that are the most basic building blocks of our theory of consumer choice.

To introduce these it is useful to think of collections or bundles of goods. To simplify, let’s identify two bundles, A and B.  The way we think of preferences always boils down to comparing two bundles.  Even if we are choosing among three or more bundles, we can always proceed by comparing pairs and eliminating the lesser bundle until we are left with our choice.

When we call something a good, we mean exactly that – something that a consumer likes and enjoys consuming.  Something that a consumer might not like we call a bad.  The fewer bads consumed, the happier a consumer is.  To keep things simple, we will focus only on goods, but it is easy to incorporate bads into the same framework by considering their absence – the fewer the bads the better.

The three fundamental assumptions about preferences are:

  1. Completeness:  We say preferences are complete when a consumer can always say one of the following about two bundles: A is preferred to B, B is preferred to A or A is equally good as B
  2. Transitivity: We say preferences are transitive if they are internally consistent: if A is preferred to B and B is preferred to C, then it must be that A is preferred to C.
  3. More is Better:  If bundle A represents more of at least one good, and no less of any other good, than bundle B, then A is preferred to B.

The most important results of our model of consumer behavior hold when we only assume completeness and transitivity, but life is much easier if we assume more is better as well.  If we assume free disposal (we can get rid of extra goods at no cost) the assumption that more is better seems reasonable. It is certainly the case that more is not worse in that situation and so to keep things simple we’ll maintain the standard assumption that we prefer more of a good to less.

Our model works well when these assumptions are valid, which seems to be most of the time in most situations. However, sometimes these assumptions do not apply.  For instance, in order to have complete and transitive preferences, we must know something about the goods in the bundle.  Imagine an American who does not speak Hindi entering an Indian restaurant where the menu is entirely in Hindi.  Without the aid of translation, the customer cannot act as economic theory would predict.

1.2 Graphing Preferences with Indifference Curves

Learning Objective 1.2: Define and draw an indifference curve.

Individual preferences, given the basic assumptions, can be represented using something called indifference curves.  An indifference curve is a graph of all of the combinations of bundles that a consumer prefers equally.  In other words, the consumer would be just as happy consuming any of them.  Representing preferences graphically is a great way to understand both preferences and how the consumer choice model works – so it is worth mastering them early in your study of microeconomics.

Bundles can contain many goods, but to simplify, we will consider only pairs of goods.  At first, this may seem impossibly restrictive but it turns out that we don’t really lose generality in so doing. We can always consider one good in the pair to be, collectively, all other consumption goods.  What the two-good restriction does so well is to help us see the tradeoffs in consuming more of one good and less of another.

Figure 1.2.1 Bundles and Indifference Curves


Figure 1.2.1 is a graph with two goods on the axes: the weekly consumption of burritos and the weekly consumption of sandwiches for a college student.  In the middle of the graph is point A, which represents a bundle of both burritos (read from the horizontal axis) and sandwiches (read from the vertical axis).

Now we can ask what bundles are better, worse, or the same in terms of satisfaction to this college student.  Clearly bundles that contain less of both goods, like bundle D, are worse than A, B or C because they violate the more is a better assumption.  Equally clear is that bundles that contain more of both goods, like bundle E, are better than A, B, C, and D because they satisfy the more is better assumption.

To create an indifference curve we want to identify bundles that this college student is indifferent about consuming.  If a bundle has more burritos the student would have to have fewer sandwiches and vice versa. By finding all the bundles that are just as good as A, like B and C, and connecting them with a line, we create an indifference curvelike the one in the middle.

Notice that Figure 1.2.1 includes several indifference curves.  Each curve represents a different level of overall satisfaction that the student can achieve via burrito/sandwich bundles. A curve further out from the origin represents a higher level of satisfaction than a curve closer to the origin.

Notice also that these curves share a number of characteristics: they slope downward, they do not cross and they are all bowed in. We explore these properties in more detail in the next section.

1.3 Properties of Indifference Curves

Learning Objective 1.3: Relate the properties of indifference curves to assumptions about preference.

As introduced in Section 1.2, indifference curves have three key properties:

  • they are downward sloping
  • they do not cross
  • they are bowed in (a non-technical way of saying they are convex to the origin).

For simplicity and clarity, from here on we will describe preferences that lead to indifference curves with these three properties as standard preferences.  This will be our default assumption – that consumers have standard preferences unless otherwise noted.  As we will see in this module, there are other types of preferences that are common as well and we will continue to study both the standard type and the other types as we progress through the material.

To understand the first two properties, it’s useful to think about what happen if they were not true.

Figure 1.3.1 Upward Sloping Indifference Curves Violate the More-is-Better Assumption

Think about indifference curves that slope upward as in figure 1.3.1.  In this case we have two bundles on the same indifference curve, A and B but B has more of both burritos and sandwiches than does A.  So this violates the assumption of more is better.  More is better implies indifference curves are downward sloping.

Figure 1.3.2: Crossing Indifference Curves Violate the Transitivity Assumption

Similarly, consider Figure 1.3.2. In this figure there are two indifference curves that cross.  Now consider bundle A on one of the indifference curves.  It represents more of both goods than bundle C that lies on the other indifference curve.  Because the bundle B lies on the same indifference curve as bundle C the two bundles should be equally preferred and therefore A should be preferred to B and C. B also represents more of both goods than bundle D and therefore B should be preferred to D. However D is on the same indifference curve as A, so B should be preferred to A.   Since A can’t be preferred to B and B preferred to A at the same time, this is a violation of our assumptions of transitivity and more is better.  Transitivity and more is better imply that indifference curves do not cross.

Now we come to the third property: indifference curves bow in.  This property comes from a fourth assumption about preferences, which we can add to the assumptions discussed in Section 1.1:

  1. Consumers like variety.

The assumption that consumers prefer variety is not necessary, but still applies in many situations.  For example, most consumers would probably prefer to eat both sandwiches and burritos during a week and not just one or the other (remember this is for consumers who consider them both goods – who like them).  In fact, if you had only sandwiches to eat for a week, you’d probably be willing to give up a lot of sandwiches for a few burritos and vice versa.  Whereas if you had reasonably equal amounts of both you’d be willing to trade one for the other but at closer to 1 to 1 ratios.  Notice that if we graph this we naturally get bowed in indifference curves, as shown in Figure 1.3.3. Preference for variety implies indifference curves are bowed in.

Figure 1.3.3 Preference for Variety Means that Indifference Curves are Bowed In.

Remember these three key points about preferences and indifference curves:

  1. More is better implies indifference curves are downward sloping.
  2. Transitivity and more is better imply indifference curves do not cross.
  3. Preference for variety implies indifference curves are bowed in.

1.4 Marginal Rate of Substitution

Learning Objective 1.4: Define marginal rate of substitution.

From now on we will assume that consumers like variety and that indifference curves are bowed in. However, it is worth considering examples on either extreme: perfect substitutes and perfect complements.

When we move along an indifference curve we can think of a consumer substituting one good for another.  Two bundles on the same indifference curve, which represent the same satisfaction from consumption, have one thing in common: they represent more of one good and less of the other.   This makes sense given our assumption of ‘more is better’; if more of one good makes you better off, then you must have less of the other good in order to maintain the same level of satisfaction.

In economics we have a more technical way of expressing this tradeoff: the marginal rate of substitution.  The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the amount of one good a consumer is willing to give up to get one more unit of another good and maintain the same level of satisfaction. This is one of the most important concepts in economics because it is critical to understanding consumer choice.

Mathematically, we express the marginal rate of substitution for two generic goods like this:

MRS=ΔAΔB

where Δ indicates a change in the quantity of the good.

In the case of our student consuming burritos and sandwiches, the expression would be:

MRS=ΔSandwichesΔBurritos

For example suppose at his current consumption bundle, 5 burritos and 4 sandwiches weekly, Luca is willing to give up 2 burritos to get one more sandwich.  Another way of saying the same thing is that Luca is indifferent between consuming 5 burritos and 4 sandwiches in a week or 3 burritos and 5 sandwiches in a week. The MRS for Luca at that point is:

MRS=ΔSandwichesΔBurritos=21=2

Note that the MRS is negative because it represents a tradeoff: more sandwiches for fewer burritos.

Figure 1.4.1 illustrates the marginal rate of substitution for burritos and sandwiches graphically.

Figure 1.4.1 Marginal rate of substitution for burritos and sandwiches.

Notice that Figure 1.4.1 illustrates a change in the good on the vertical axis (sandwiches) over the change in the good on the horizontal axis (burritos). This is the same as saying the rise over the run. From this discussion and graph, it should be clear that the MRS is same as the slope of the indifference curve at any given point along it.

1.5 Perfect Complements and Perfect Substitutes

Learning Objective 1.5: Use indifference curves to illustrate perfect complements and perfect substitutes.

We have now studied the assumptions upon which our model of consumer behavior is built:

  1. completeness
  2. transitivity
  3. more is better
  4. love of variety

We have also seen how these assumptions govern the properties of indifference curves.

It is worth taking a moment to think about two other types of preference relations that are special cases but not uncommon: perfect complements and perfect substitutes.

Perfect Complements

Perfect complements are goods that consumers want to consume only in fixed proportions.

Consider the example of an iPod Shuffle and earphones. An iPod Shuffle is useless without earphones and earphones are useless without an iPod Shuffle, but put them together and, voila, you have a portable stereo, which is worth quite a lot.  An extra set of earphones doesn’t increase the usefulness of the iPod and an extra iPod doesn’t increase the usefulness of the earphones.  So these are things that we consume in a fixed proportion: one iPod goes with one set of earphones. We call such preference relations perfect complements

Figure 1.5.1 illustrates the process of drawing indifference curves for perfect complements.

Figure 1.5.1: Indifference Curves for Goods that are Perfect Complements 

In Figure 1.5.1, when we start with a bundle of one iPod and one set of earbuds (as in bundle A), what are the other bundles that are just as good to the consumer?  Two sets of earbuds and one iPod is no better than one set of earbuds and one iPod, so bundle B lies on the same indifference curve.  The same is true for two iPods and one set of earbuds, as in bundle C.  From this example, we can see that indifference curves for perfect complements have right angles.

Perfect Substitutes

Perfect substitutes are goods about which consumers are indifferent as to which to consume.

That is, one unit of one good is just as good as one unit of another good.  Both Morton and Diamond Crystal are brands of table salt.  For most consumers, a teaspoon of one salt is just as good as a teaspoon of the other regardless of the amount possessed by the consumer.  We call goods like these perfect substitutes.

Drawing indifference curves for perfect substitutes is straightforward as shown in Figure 1.5.2.

Figure 1.5.2: Indifference Curves for Goods that are Perfect Substitutes 

мBundle A in Figure 1.5.2 contains 5 teaspoons of each type of salt. This is just as good to the consumer as a bundle with 10 teaspoons of Morton salt and zero teaspoons of Diamond Crystal as in bundle B. It is also just as good as the 10 teaspoons of Diamond Crystal and zero teaspoons of Morton in bundle C.

You can think of perfect complements and perfect substitutes as polar extremes of preference relations. Figure 1.5.3 shows how a typical indifference curve lies between perfect complements and perfect substitutes.  You should understand when graphically represented, that the indifference curve for well-behaved preferences lies between perfect complements and perfect substitutes.

Figure 1.5.3: The Relationship between Indifference Curves for Well Behaved Preferences and Perfect Complements and Substitutes

1.6 Policy Example: The Hybrid Car Tax Credit and Consumer Preference

Learning Objective 1.6: Apply indifference curves to the policy of a hybrid car tax credit

The issue of consumer preferences is central to the real-world policy question posed at the beginning of this module.

“Traffic jam” from Lynac on Flickr is licensed under CC BY-NC

Recall that we are assuming that the tax credit will cause the average fuel economy of U.S. cars to double. So, from a consumer behavior perspective, one of the things we want to know in evaluating the policy is whether this improvement in gas mileage will cause an equivalent decrease in the demand for gasoline.  In other words, the consumer decision is about the tradeoff of purchasing gasoline to travel in a car versus all of the other uses of the money spent on gas.

 We can apply the principle of preferences and the assumptions we make about them to this particular question by drawing indifference curves, as shown in Figure 1.6.1

Figure 1.6.1: Indifference Curve for Miles Drives versus Money Spent on All Other Goods

We can label one axis of the indifference curve map “miles driven” and the other “money for other consumption.”  Doing so illustrates how confining ourselves to only two dimensions is really not that confining at all.  By considering the other axis as money for all other purchases we are really looking at the general trade-off between one particular consumption good and everything else that a consumer could possibly consume.

So, what would our indifference curve look like? As before it would be downward sloping – surely traveling more by car affords the consumer more freedom of movement and therefore more consumption choices, both of which are a good. The indifference curves would not cross for the same reasons discussed in section 1.3. But what about the principle of more is better?  The point here is to again think about the principle of free disposal: as long as the ability to drive more miles is not bad (and it is hard to imagine how it could be) then more miles are never worse.

The remaining question is whether the preference for variety is a good assumption in this case.  It is helpful to consider the extremes: for those consumers who own cars, never driving any miles is probably not very practical.  Likewise spending one’s entire income only on expenses relating to driving one’s car is unappealing.  A good assumption, then, is that most people with a car would prefer some combination of miles driven and other consumption to either extreme and we can draw our indifference curves as convex to the origin.

We are not yet in a position to say much about the policy itself, but we have one piece of the model we will use to analyze it. With this indifference curve we can move on to the other pieces of the model that we will study in Modules 2, 3 and 4.

Exploring the Policy Question

  1. Suppose that a typical consumer is concerned about how his or her individual driving habits are negatively impacting the environment. How might such a change in attitude change the shape of the consumer’s indifference curves?

https://bit.ly/3c7cDIJ