вторник, 28 марта 2023 г.

Module 10: Market Equilibrium: Supply and Demand

 


“Chinatown Scene” from binaryscalper on Pixabay is licensed under CC BY

THE POLICY QUESTION
SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROVIDE PUBLIC MARKETPLACES?

In the Capitol Hill neighborhood of Washington, DC, the Eastern Market is a large building and grounds owned and operated by the city government. Farmers, bakers, cheese makers, and other merchants of food, arts, and crafts assemble there to sell their wares. Marketplaces like it were once a common feature of cities in the United States and Europe but are now a relative rarity. Many have disappeared due to citizens questioning whether the government should be supporting these marketplaces.

So why does the government play a role in providing some markets? The answer is found in the way markets create benefits for the citizens they serve. In this chapter, we explore how prices and quantities are set in market equilibrium, how changes in supply and demand factors cause market equilibrium to adjust, and how we measure the benefit of markets to society.

Markets are often private in the sense that the government is not involved in their creation or presence; instead, they are generated by the desire of private individuals to engage in an exchange for a particular good. Sometimes, however, the government plays an active role in establishing and managing markets. At the end of the chapter, we will study why this occurs, using the Eastern Market as an example.

EXPLORING THE POLICY QUESTION

  • Is public investment in marketplaces justified and if so why?

10.1 WHAT IS A MARKET?

Learning Objective 10.1: Identify the characteristics of a market.

In chapter 9, we found out that the market supply curve comes from the cost structure of individual firms, which in turn comes from their technology, as we discovered in chapter 7. In chapter 5, we found out where the demand curve comes from—the individual utility maximization problems of individual consumers. In both cases, we assumed the demand for and supply of a specific good or service. In other words, we were describing a particular market.

market is characterized as a particular location where a specific good or service is being sold at a defined time. So, for example, we might talk about

  • the market for eggs in Nashville, Tennessee, in April 2016;
  • the market for rolled aluminum in the United States in 2015; or
  • the market for radiological diagnostic services worldwide in the last decade.

In addition, for whatever item, time, and place we describe, there must be both buyers and sellers in order for a market to exist. A market is where buyers and sellers exchange or where there is both demand and supply.

We tend to talk about markets somewhat loosely when studying economics. For example, we might discuss the market for orange juice and leave the time and place undefined in order to keep things simple. Or we might just say that we are looking at the market for denim jeans in the United States. The difficulty with these simplifications is that we can lose sight of the basic assumptions about markets that are necessary for our analysis of them.

The six necessary assumptions for markets are the following:

  1. A market is for a single good or service.
  2. All goods or services bought and sold in a market are identical.
  3. The good or service sells for a single price.
  4. All consumers know everything about the product, including how much they value it.
  5. There are many buyers and sellers, and they are known to each other and can interact.
  6. All the costs and benefits of a transaction accrue only to the buyers and sellers who engage in them.

These assumptions are actually pretty easy to understand. They guarantee that the buyers who value the good more than it costs sellers to produce it will find a seller willing to sell to them. In other words, there are no transactions that don’t happen because the buyer doesn’t know how much they like the product or because a buyer can’t find a seller, or vice versa.

Of course, the assumptions describe an ideal market. In reality, many markets are not exactly like this, and later, in chapters 2021, and 22, we will examine what happens when these assumptions fail to hold.

10.2 MARKET EQUILIBRIUM: THE SUPPLY AND DEMAND CURVES TOGETHER

Learning Objective 10.2: Determine the equilibrium price and quantity for a market, both graphically and mathematically.

Market equilibrium is the point where the quantity supplied by producers and the quantity demanded by consumers are equal. When we put the demand and supply curves together, we can determine the equilibrium price: the price at which the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied. In figure 10.2.1, the equilibrium price is shown as , and it is precisely where the demand curve and supply curve cross. This makes sense—the demand curve gives the quantity demanded at every price and the supply curve gives the quantity supplied at every price so there is one price that they have in common, which is at the intersection of the two curves.


Figure 10.2.1 The supply and demand curves and market equilibrium

Graphing the supply and demand curves to locate their intersection is one way to find the equilibrium price. We can also find this quantity mathematically. Consider a demand curve for stereo headphones that is described by the following function:

=1,80020

Note that in general, we draw graphs of functions with the independent variable on the horizontal axis and the dependent variable on the vertical axis. In the case of supply and demand curves, however, we draw them with quantity on the horizontal axis and price on the vertical. Because of this, it is sometimes easier to express the demand relationship as an inverse demand curve: the demand curve expressed as price as a function of quantity. In our example, this would be

=900.05.

This is just the original demand curve solved for  instead of . In the inverse demand curve, the vertical intercept is easy to see from the equation: demand for headphones stops at the price of $90. No consumer is willing to pay $90 or more for headphones.

Similarly, the supply curve can be represented as a mathematical function. For example, consider a supply curve described by the following function:

=501,000

Similar to the demand curve, we can express this as an inverse supply curve: the supply curve expressed as price as a function of quantity. In this case, the inverse supply curve would be

=200.03.

Here the vertical intercept, $20, gives us the minimum price to get a seller to sell headphones. At prices of $20 or less, there will be no supply. So we know that the equilibrium price should be between $20 and $90.

Solving for the equilibrium price and quantity is simply a matter of setting = and solving for the price that makes this equality happen. In our example, setting = yields

1,80020=501,000

or

70=2,800

or

=$40

At =$40, the quantity demanded and supplied can be found from the demand and supply curves:

=1,80020(40)=1,000

=50(40)1,000=1,000

That these two quantities match is no accident; this was the condition we set at the outset—that quantity supplied equals quantity demanded. So we know that a price of $40 per unit is the equilibrium price.

These supply and demand curves for headphones are graphed in figure 10.2.2 below, and their intersection confirms the equilibrium price we calculated mathematically.



Figure 10.2.2 Explicit supply and demand curves for headphones

Note that we have also identified the equilibrium quantity—the quantity at which supply equals demand. At $40 per unit, one thousand headphones are demanded, and exactly one thousand headphones are supplied. The equilibrium quantity has nothing to do with any kind of coordination or communication among the buyers and sellers; it has only to do with the price in the market. Seeing a unit price of $40, consumers demand one thousand units. Independently, sellers who see that price will choose to supply exactly one thousand units.

10.3 EXCESS SUPPLY AND DEMAND

Learning Objective 10.3: Calculate and graph excess supply and excess demand.

It makes sense that the equilibrium price is the one that equates quantity demanded with quantity supplied, but how does the market get to this equilibrium? Is this just an accident? No. The market price will automatically adjust to a point where supply matches demand. Excess supply or demand in a market will trigger such an adjustment.

To understand this equilibrating feature of the market price, let’s return to our headphones example. Suppose the price is $50 instead of $40. At this price, we know from the supply curve that fifteen hundred units will be supplied to the market. Also, from the demand curve, we know that eight hundred units will be demanded. Thus there will be an excess supply of seven hundred units, as shown in figure 10.2.3.

Excess supply occurs when, at a given price, firms supply more of a good than what consumers demand. These are goods that have been produced by the firms that supply the market and have not found any willing buyers. Firms will want to sell these goods and know that by lowering the price, more buyers will appear. So this excess supply of goods will lead to a price decrease. The price will continue to fall as long as the excess supply conditions exist. In other words, price will continue to fall until it reaches $40.



Figure 10.2.3 Excess supply of headphones at a price of $50

The same logic applies to situations where the price is below the intersection of supply and demand. Suppose the price of headphones is $30. We know from the demand curve that at this price, consumers will demand twelve hundred units. We also know from the supply curve that at this price, suppliers will supply five hundred units. So at $30, there will be excess demand of seven hundred units, as shown in figure 10.2.4.

Excess demand occurs when, at a given price, consumers demand more of a good than firms supply. Consumers who are not able to find goods to purchase will offer more money in an effort to entice suppliers to supply more. Suppliers who are offered more money will increase supply, and this will continue to happen as long as the price is below $40 and there is excess demand.



Figure 10.2.4 Excess demand for headphones at a price of $30

Only at a price of $40 is the pressure for prices to rise or fall relieved and will the price remain constant.

10.4 MEASURING WELFARE AND PARETO EFFICIENCY

Learning Objective 10.4: Calculate consumer surplus, producer surplus, and deadweight loss for a market.

From our study of markets so far, it is clear that they can contribute to the economic well-being of both buyers and sellers. The term welfare, as it is used in economics, refers to the economic well-being of society as a whole, including producers and consumers. We can measure welfare for particular market situations.

To understand the economic concept of welfare—and how to quantify it—it is useful to think about the weekly farmers’ market in Ithaca, New York. The market is a place where local growers can sell their produce directly to consumers throughout the summer. It is very successful, and many local residents go to the market to buy produce. Now consider the specific example of tomatoes. What is this market worth to the tomato sellers and buyers that transact in the market?

Suppose a farmer has a minimum willingness-to-accept price of $1 for an heirloom tomato. This price could be based on the farmer’s cost of production or the value she places on consuming the tomato herself. Suppose also that there is a consumer who really wants an heirloom tomato to add to his salad that evening and is willing to pay up to $3 for one. If these two people meet each other at the market and agree on a price of $2, how much benefit do they each get?

The seller receives $2, and it cost her $1 to provide the tomato, so she is $1 better off, the difference between what she received and what she would have accepted for the tomato. Likewise, the buyer pays $2 but receives $3 in benefit from the tomato, since that was his willingness to pay; his net benefit is the difference, or $1. The seller and buyer are both $1 better off because they had the opportunity to meet and transact. Without this opportunity, the seller would have stayed at home with the tomato and been no better or worse off, and the buyer would not have a tomato for his salad but would be no better or worse off.

The difference between the price received and the willingness-to-accept price is called the producer surplus (). The difference between the willingness-to-pay price and the price paid is called the consumer surplus (). The sum of these two surpluses is called total surplus (). So the producer surplus in the tomato example is $1, the consumer surplus is $1, and the total surplus is $2. This is the surplus generated by one transaction; if we add up all such transactions in the market, we get a measure of the consumer and producer surplus from the market.

Quantifying surplus for an entire market is easy to do with a graph. Let’s return to our previous example of headphones and find the consumer and producer surplus.

Figure 10.4.1 shows that the consumer surplus is the area above the equilibrium price and below the demand curve—the green triangle in the figure. Similarly, the producer surplus is the area below the equilibrium price and above the supply curve—the red triangle in the figure. The area of each surplus triangle is easy to calculate using the formula for the area of a triangle: 12, where  is base and  is height.



Figure 10.4.1 Consumer surplus and producer surplus in the market for headphones

In the case of consumer surplus, the triangle has a base of one thousand, the distance from the origin to , and a height of $50, the difference between $90, the vertical intercept, and , which is $40.

Consumer surplus=12(1,000)($50)=$25,000

Similarly,

Producer surplus=12(1,000)($20)=$10,000.

Total surplus created by this market is the sum of the two, or $35,000. This is the measure of how much value the market creates through its enabling of these transactions. Without the ability to come together in this market, the buyers and sellers would miss out on the opportunity to capture this surplus.

We say that a market is efficient when the entire potential surplus has been created. Such a market is an example of Pareto efficiency—an allocation of goods and services in which no redistribution can occur without making someone worse off. Think about the distribution of goods in the headphones example. All the buyers and sellers that transact are made better off by the transaction because they gain some surplus from it. If they didn’t, they would not voluntarily trade. None of the trades that shouldn’t happen do. For example, if there were more than one thousand units exchanged, it would mean sellers were selling to buyers who valued the good less than the sellers’ cost of production, where the supply curve is above the demand curve, and one or both of the parties would be worse off because of the exchange.

Another way to see that the market equilibrium outcome is efficient is if we arbitrarily limit the number of goods exchanged to nine hundred. Let’s call this maximum quantity restriction ¯, where the bar above the Q indicates that it is fixed at that quantity. There are one hundred surplus-creating transactions that don’t occur; this cannot be an efficient outcome because the entire potential surplus has not been created. The lost potential surplus has a name, deadweight loss(): the loss of total surplus that occurs when there is an inefficient allocation of resources. The blue triangle in figure 10.4.2 represents this deadweight loss.



Figure 10.4.2 Deadweight loss from a quantity constraint

We can calculate the value of the deadweight loss precisely, again using the formula for the area of a triangle. Since the demand function is =1,80020, the point on the demand curve that results in a demand of nine hundred is a price of $45. Similarly, if the supply function is given as =501,000, the point on the supply curve that results in a quantity supplied of nine hundred is a price of $38. Thus the base of the triangle is $45 − $38, or $7, and the height is the difference between the one thousand units that are sold in the absence of a restriction and the nine-hundred-unit restricted quantity, or one hundred. So

=12($7)(100)=$350.

10.5 POLICY EXAMPLE
SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROVIDE PUBLIC MARKETPLACES?

Learning Objective 10.5: Apply the concept of economic welfare to the policy of publicly supported marketplaces.

The first question in determining whether a case can be made for the public provision of marketplaces, such as the Eastern Market in Washington, DC, is what would occur in the absence of such a market. If the buyers and sellers in these markets could easily access other markets, then it would be hard to argue that the marketplace is providing a net benefit. Similarly, if the commercial activity that takes place in this market is simply a diversion of similar activity that would have taken place elsewhere, then it is likely that there is little to no net benefit. So for the sake of this exercise, we will assume that the marketplace is providing an opportunity to these buyers and sellers that they would not otherwise have.

So given this assumption, are these marketplaces valuable? The simple answer, as long as transactions are occurring, is yes. We can see this from a simple diagram of a market for an individual good, let’s say fresh apples, that exists within the Eastern Market (figure 10.5.1).


Figure 10.5.1 The market for apples in the Eastern Market

There is clearly a surplus being created by the apple transactions that take place within the market. This in itself is the primary argument for the marketplace. Buyers and sellers are able to transact and become better off for it. The value to those individuals is measured by surplus.

But a complete answer must compare the value to society of the markets to the cost to society of the marketplace itself. Does the total surplus created by the marketplace justify the cost?

Let’s return now to the key assumption—that a market for fresh apples would not exist without government support. Is this a reasonable assumption?

In the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, when many public markets were founded, transportation was difficult, and bringing fresh food to support urban population centers was something local governments commonly did. Today, transportation is not nearly as difficult or costly. But although many areas are well served by grocery stores, where it is reasonable to expect customers will find fresh fruits and vegetables, other locations are characterized by food deserts. Food deserts are defined as urban neighborhoods and rural towns without ready access to fresh, healthy, and affordable food. Instead of supermarkets and grocery stores, these communities may have no food access or are served only by fast-food restaurants and convenience stores that offer few healthy, affordable food options. The lack of access contributes to a poor diet and can lead to higher levels of obesity and other diet-related diseases, such as diabetes and heart disease (US Department of Agriculture [USDA]).

The USDA estimates that 23.5 million people in the United States live in food deserts.

Although the Capitol Hill neighborhood experienced some hard times in the past, today it is prosperous and well served by grocery stores. So the need for government support of the Eastern Market there is less clear. In chapter 21, we will explore public goods and externalities in detail and become better equipped to fully explore this issue.

EXPLORING THE POLICY QUESTION

  1. What other kinds of marketplaces can you think of that the government aids by providing infrastructure?
  2. Airports allow the market for airline travel to exist in a functional way. Most airports in the United States are run by local governments. Using the topics explored in this chapter, give a justification for government expenditures on airports.
  3. Should the District of Columbia government spend money on a market that primarily serves one neighborhood? Give reasons for and against.

LEARN: KEY TOPICS

Terms

Market equilibrium
Inverse demand curve
Inverse supply curve

The supply curve expressed as price as a function of quantity:

=200.03

Equilibrium price
Equilibrium quantity
Excess demand
Excess supply
Welfare
Producer surplus
Consumer surplus
Total surplus
Pareto efficiency
Deadweight loss

Graphs

The supply and demand curves and market equilibrium
Explicit supply and demand curves
Excess supply at a price of $50
Excess demand at a price of $30
Consumer surplus and producer surplus
Deadweight loss from a quantity constraint
A typical goods market in the eastern market

Equations

Quantity supplied

=501000

Determining Q* and P*

P=MC(Q)

The above equation utilizes the relationship between quantity and price to determine a starting algorithm for drafting a supply curve. Review this relationship in chapter 9.

Inverse supply curve

=200.03

Quantity demanded

Derived from max production and minimum price to cover costs with profit.

=1,80020

Inverse demand curve

=900.05

The original equation set to solve for P. In this inverse curve, the vertical intercept is very clear: demand for this product stops at $90. No one is willing to pay more than $90 for the product.

Solving for equilibrium price () and equilibrium quantity 

Solving for the equilibrium price and quantity is simply a matter of setting

=

and solving for the price that makes this equality happen. In our example, setting = yields

1,80020=501,000

or

70=2,800

or

=$40

At =$40, the quantity demanded and supplied can be found from the demand and supply curves:

=1,80020(40)=1,000
=50(40)1,000=1,000

If the proper  and  have been found, the two equations should be equal.

Issues of excess and deadweight loss ()

Quantifying surplus is easy to do with a graph, see figure 10.4.1 in full-size via link or half-size below:

the consumer surplus is the area above the equilibrium price and below the demand curve—the green triangle in the figure. Similarly, the producer surplus is the area below the equilibrium price and above the supply curve—the red triangle in the figure. The area of each surplus triangle is easy to calculate using the formula for the area of a triangle, where  is base and  is height:

12

Utilizing figures from the graph, the following formulas can be derived:

Consumer surplus

Consumer surplus=12(1,000)($50)=$25,000

or

Consumer surplus=12()()

where the area equals the total dollar amount of producer surplus, the base () is the distance from the origin to , and the height () is the difference between the maximum willing to pay price , or the y-intercept, and . This can also be written thusly:

=12(()(())

where  is the origin of the supply curve and  is the vertical intercept of the y-axis, and also the maximum price that anyone is willing to pay for the product.

Producer surplus

Producer surplus=12(1,000)($20)=$10,000

or

Producer surplus=12()()=

where the area equals the total dollar amount of producer surplus, the base () is the distance from the origin to , and the height () is minimum price. This can also be written thusly:

=12()()=

where  is the origin of the supply curve and  is the minimum willingness-to-accept price.

Total surplus

The sum of  and 

=+

Deadweight loss ()

The loss of total surplus that occurs when there is an inefficient allocation of resources.

=12()()

Where  is the price determined by the supply/demand curves to be viable at the current output, . See Figure 10.4.2 for full-size or see half-size below. Figure 10.4.2 illustrates utilizing a graph to develop a  equation:


If a firm produces 900 headphones, but the  satates that 1000 is the optimum output, the lost surplus price would then equate to the difference between the price for 900 units (,in this case900), or $38, and the , or $45. Thus the denominator would be 100 (1000-900) and the numerator $7 ($45-$38). The equation would look thus:

=12($7)(100)=$350

https://cutt.ly/44ZmRFt

понедельник, 27 марта 2023 г.

Welfare economics I: Definition and main economists

 


Summary

Welfare economics analyses different states in which markets or the economy can be. Its main objective is to find an indicator or measure in order to guarantee that markets are behaving optimally, thus also guaranteeing that consumer welfare is as high as possible. In this Learning Path, we learn about the basics of welfare economics.

Welfare economics are a part of normative economics which objective is to evaluate different situations of a given economic system, in order to choose the best one.

Its study can be traced back to Adam Smith, who related an increase of welfare with an increase on production, and to Jeremy Bentham, whose utilitarian views made him think that welfare was equal to the sum of individuals utilities or, in other words, to a “social” utility.

Traditional welfare economics is based on the work of three neoclassical economistsAlfred Marshall stated that consumer’s welfare was the consumer’s surplus, and therefore was measurable in monetary units. Vilfredo Pareto would criticize this cardinal view, and would be the economist who built a true theory of welfare economics in his book “Manual of Political Economy”, 1906: based on the principles of unanimity and individualism, he designed what nowadays is known as the Pareto Optimality, which would become the core of welfare economics. Later, Pigou wrote “The Economics of Welfare”, 1920, stating that a definition of social welfare must include both efficiency and equity.

During the XXth century, welfare economics developed quickly. Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks’ compensation criteria, and its following critics by Scitovsky, Little and Paul Samuelson, which aim was to find some way of classification of different optima. Also Bergson’s social welfare function, and Kenneth Arrow’s impossibility theorem, proving the former could not be identified. The theory of second best, developed by Lipsey and Lancaster, aimed at finding an optimum when Pareto optimality could not be found. Finally, the increasing use of cost-benefit analysis marks the validity of welfare economics nowadays.


Arthur C. Pigou



Pigou was a British economist (1877-1959), disciple of Alfred Marshall, whom he succeeded as a professor at Cambridge. Pigou is remembered above all as a precursor of welfare economics, for his books “Wealth and Welfare”, 1912, and “The Economics of Welfare”, 1920, in which he used measures of national income and its distribution in order to understand how wealth and welfare are related. He is also remembered for making a distinction between different degrees of price discrimination.

Being part of the Cambridge school, Pigou used common tools derived from neoclassical economics, such as marginalism, amongst others.


Vilfredo Pareto



Pareto was an economist and sociologist of Italian origin, born in Paris (1848-1923), who taught at the University of Lausanne, as well as previously did his mentor, Léon Walras. They both were part of the Lausanne School, which is considered, along with the Austrian School, as the birthplace of marginalism and neoclassical economics.

His chief works were “Course of Political Economy”, 1896-97, and “Manual of Political Economy”, 1906. Among Pareto’s contributions, we can highlight the graphical development of Edgeworth box, as well as an improvement on the way indifference curves are drawn, and studies on the personal distribution of income.

In his studies of the late nineteenth century, Pareto found some regularity in the personal distribution of income in different countries. From that regularity, he determined a series of economic and sociological conclusions, which became known afterwards as Pareto’s Laws. He also studied some regularities in businesses, where concentration was the explanation for the fact that many companies get 80% of their revenue from only 20% of its products.

Nowadays, however, he is mostly known for the Pareto optimal, a notion widely used in game theory and welfare economics.

https://cutt.ly/s4JtoZW