Показаны сообщения с ярлыком competitive markets. Показать все сообщения
Показаны сообщения с ярлыком competitive markets. Показать все сообщения

пятница, 30 июня 2023 г.

Competitive Analysis

 



Competition in the market is one of the key concepts in the economy. First of all, competition is rivalry. It is rivalry that helps companies not to stand still and move forward, improving their positions. Therefore, you need to pay special attention to this area. To always be up to date, you must constantly monitor your competitors, this applies to both existing and potential ones. You should study the main players in the market in detail to finally understand their weaknesses and strengths, this will help you improve the efficiency of your company. Also, in the competitive analysis, we should determine our place in the market in relation to competitors, this will give us an understanding of where to go next and what needs to be done for this.

Competitive Analysis Based on Comparison

One of the most common methods of conducting competitive analysis is comparison. This is a logical method of competitive analysis, the point is you make a list of competitors and criteria by which you will then compare them, and then draw conclusions based on this data. It is possible to distinguish the main stages of its implementation:


Object

At this stage, we define the main idea of the study in total: why we conduct it (the goal) and general positions. To do this, you can describe the situation of the industry as a whole, the state of the market, the current situation in which your company is located, external factors that affect both the industry and your company, the problems that the organization has faced and that need to be solved with the help of this study.

Competitors

In this section, we compile lists of competitors. There are different approaches to selecting competitors for analysis.

Competitors can be divided into the following groups:

  • direct competitors are companies that offer exactly the same or similar products or services that work with you in the same market, aimed at the same segment of consumers. Direct competitors represent the most serious competition for you, as they can entice your customers with various loyalty programs, lower prices, more favorable terms of cooperation, etc.,
  • indirect competitors are companies that offer a substitute product but work for the same target audience. Indirect competitors also pose a threat to you, although on a smaller scale than direct competitors. First, they attract some of your customers, and, secondly, they can become direct competitors for you in the future.
  • prospective competitors are companies that may pose a threat to you in the future. This type of competition is quite unpredictable, so it is difficult to track them and predict the next steps. These can be:
  1. Existing companies that are not yet in your market, but that may appear at any time
  2. Indirect competitors
  3. A company that can offer a solution to the problem for consumers that is different from your product

Another option for making a list of competitors is based on the number of participants.

  • complete list. In this case, you list all the competitors. This is quite a time-consuming path since most companies have a huge number of competitors, so you will have to collect and process too much information. This approach is preferred for companies that have a small number of competitors.
  • incomplete list. It is compiled depending on the research objectives, for example, the following areas can be distinguished:
  1. key players. Lists the main companies in the market that are the driving force in this industry and can be an example of successful solutions and strategies. Here we can talk about such a concept as benchmarking. Benchmarking is the ability to find or identify best practices and techniques that other firms use, to study them, and apply them to your business.
  2. the closest competitors are competitors operating in the geographical areas of the market that are close to you in terms of position.
  3. three main competitors. You can limit your list by highlighting your top three competitors.

Whatever method you choose to compile the list (suggested in this article or your own), it should in any case meet your needs and research goals.

Parameters

In accordance with this section, you define the criteria by which you will compare competitors and your company. The criteria are also selected individually for each company, based on the set research goals. You can select the following parameters and analyze them separately, for example, price, quality, quantity, product/service promotion activities, customer service, brand awareness/loyalty, market share, distribution, technology, personnel, target audience, etc.

You can group the criteria and use the key success factors (KSFs). KSFs are the main indicators by which a firm has an advantage.

For example:

  • technological factors
  • production factors
  • distribution
  • marketing
  • personnel factors and other types of KSFs
Sources

At this step, you define the sources of information. The sources of information are usually divided into primary and secondary.

A primary source gives you direct access to the subject of your research. Primary sources can either be qualitative or quantitative data that you collect yourself (It can be observations, interviews and surveys, experiments) or sources produced by people directly involved in the topic (recordings of speeches, social media posts, letters, and others).

Primary information is reliable and authentic, but it is quite an expensive type of information collection and takes a lot of time.

Secondary sources describe, summarize, or discuss information or details originally presented in another source. This type of source is designed for a broad audience. Sources of secondary information collection can be articles in magazines and newspapers; advertising, presentations, promotional materials, etc.; consumer reviews, reviews of former employees of companies; website; online search; your sales department, and so on.

To get more complete information about competitors, you need to use all available sources of information.

Analysis

At this phase, you analyze the data and create a report with conclusions and suggestions.

For the convenience and clarity of the competitive analysis, you can create a table in which you will mark the received data. You can use a scoring system or a descriptive system for evaluating criteria.

The table can look like this, but you can also create your own according to your needs:

 Characteristic 1Characteristic 2Characteristic 3Characteristic 4
Competitor 1    
Competitor 2    
Competitor 3    
Your company    

When the data is collected and organized, you can also create graphs and charts.

One of the tools for data analysis is the SWOT analysis, in which you list the weaknesses and strengths of your competitors, based on which you will see the further direction of your business development.

Porter’s Five Forces Analysis

Speaking of competitive analysis, it is impossible not to mention Porter’s five forces analysis. This methodology focuses on the industry as a whole, not on its individual part or a set of industries. One industry is characterized by one of Porter’s five forces analysis.

Porter’s five forces analysis is a method of analyzing competition that helps determine the attractiveness of an industry and the profitability of doing business in it. This model was developed by the American expert in the field of economics Michael E. Porter in 1979.


Michael Porter identifies five driving forces in the market.

Threat of New Entrants

These are external potential competitors. New players open up new opportunities, they can offer innovative solutions for this market, use new technologies and resources, this can lead to changes in consumer behavior and reduce the income level of existing market participants. There are constraints for new players to enter this market. First of all, these are barriers to entry. According to M. Porter, barriers to entry include supply-side economies of scale; demand-side benefits of scale; customer switching costs; capital requirements; incumbency advantages independent of size; unequal access to distribution channels; government policy. If the barriers to entry are high, it will be more difficult for new entrants to enter this business sector, and vice versa.

Threat of Substitutes

Substitute products are similar products produced for the same consumers, similar in purpose and use, but with any differences in characteristics. Substitute products affect the price level, so they usually offer a cheaper option for the consumer, for example, due to a different production technology or the use of cheaper raw materials. The price falls, which leads to lower profits. The more attractive the price-quality ratio in substitute products, the greater the threat to the profits of companies that exist in this market. To counter this threat, it is necessary to develop a clear policy of differentiation, focus on the additional advantages of the product, and have a strong brand.

Bargaining Power of Suppliers

These are the owners of resources to produce goods in the industry. This includes raw materials, components, labor, maintenance, etc. If suppliers provide a rare product or service, they may have an impact on the company with which they cooperate (refusal of deliveries, inflated prices, unfavorable terms of transactions, etc.).

Bargaining Power of Buyers

Consumers ensure the existence of the market. They can affect competition in the market due to high requirements for the quality of products or services, which, in turn, affects the profits of companies, as the manufacturer increases its costs to improve quality. Buyers are directly connected with the price, as they want to reduce their costs, so they are constantly looking for more favorable offers. The power of buyers is high if they have a large choice and therefore decreases if the number of alternatives decreases. Companies often introduce loyalty programs to retain or attract customers.

Industry Rivalry

Here, the fight unfolds between existing competitors in this market. Thanks to this competition, companies increase advertising and promotion costs, apply different pricing strategies, develop new technologies and solutions, which leads to a decrease in the profitability of the industry.

Profitability in the market depends on the strength of the influence of competitive forces: the stronger the influence, the smaller your profit will be, and the weaker the influence, the more likely you are to get a higher profit. Thanks to the conducted research of the industry, your company will be able to find a suitable niche in the market, the influence of competitive forces in which will be minimized.

Competitive Profiling

In our article, we would also like to pay attention to another option for conducting competitive analysis – competitive profiling. Competitive profiling is the creation of a detailed portrait of competitors for a deeper understanding of their business. As a rule, it includes:

  • General description of the competitor company. History, main milestones, location, ownership and organizational structure, company leaders and management, mission and vision of the organization, the unique value proposition (UVP), financial indicators, and more.
  • Production. Factory capacity, technology, equipment, production culture, and more.
  • Products. Existing product portfolio and product line width, new products, products in development. Patents, intellectual property, know-how. The quality of products, the number of products (volume). Packaging, design.
  • Brand. Brand awareness, brand loyalty.
  • Marketing:

– Promotion and positioning

  • advertising campaigns: advertising in the media (TV, radio, periodicals, Internet), outdoor advertising, indoor advertising, social advertising, etc.
  • various types of sales promotion: contests, lotteries, loyalty programs, etc.
  • participation in exhibitions, presentations, etc.

– Distribution (analysis of channels: intermediaries (wholesaler, retailer, agent), direct deliveries, channel mix), and more.

– Prices (discounts and sales, price mark-ups)

– Segmentation, target audience, geographical coverage, and so on

– Customer service: pre-sale service, service during the sale, and after-sales service.

  • Personnel: number of employees, key employees, core competencies, leadership style, benefits, corporate programs, training, and so on.

You can also add other data to your profile. The more data you have about your competitors, the clearer you will see the overall picture of the business.

The importance of competitive analysis is very great, it allows you to learn the strengths and weaknesses of competitors, to study their strategy, goals, which will allow your company to improve the effectiveness of its actions, so it should become a necessary tool for your business.

https://www.marketing-psycho.com/

суббота, 15 апреля 2023 г.

Welfare economics I: Efficiency and optimal allocation

 

Pareto efficiency


This efficiency criterion was developed by Vilfredo Pareto in his book “Manual of Political Economy”, 1906. An allocation of goods is Pareto optimal when there is no possibility of redistribution in a way where at least one individual would be better off while no other individual ends up worse off.

A definition can also be made in two steps:

-a change from situation A to B is a Pareto improvement if at least one individual is better off without making other individuals worse off;

-B is Pareto optimal if there is no possible Pareto improvement.


This can be easily understood using an Edgeworth box. Starting from point C, two Pareto improvements can be made:

-from C to D: individual 1 would increase its utility, since a further indifference curve would be reached, while individual 2 will remain with the same utility;

-from C to E: individual 2 would maintain its utility while individual 2 increases theirs.

Once we are at point either D or E, no further Pareto improvements can be made. Therefore, D and E are Pareto optimal.

Following the same steps for every indifference curve, we can say that every point in which indifference curves from different individuals are tangent is Pareto optimal. The curve that links these infinite Pareto optima is called the contract curve.


Edgeworth box


In 1881, Francis Y. Edgeworth came up with a way of representing, using the same axis, indifference curves and the corresponding contract curve in his book “Mathematical Psychics: an Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences”. However, the representation given, using as an example the work being done by Friday and wages being paid by Robinson Crusoe, was not the one we commonly know nowadays.


It was Vilfredo Pareto, in his book “Manual of Political Economy”, 1906, who developed Edgeworth’s ideas into a more understandable and simpler diagram, which today we call the Edgeworth box.

This diagram is widely used in welfare economicsgame theory or general equilibrium theory, to name a few. It is easy to draw and can be easily explained. In the adjacent image, we can see two examples of an Edgeworth box, and how it is drawn.

The first example is mainly used for welfare economics and distribution matters. As we see, this “box” is formed using two sets of typical indifference maps, which in this case represent the indifference curves of agents A (green) and B (red), who must choose quantities of goods x and y. When the indifference map of agent B is rotated, and put on top of the map of agent A, the box is formed. When indifference curves are tangent to each other, which is the case in this example, a contract curve (blue) can be drawn using these tangency points.

Our second example is mainly used to explain Ricardian trade theory graphically. In this case, we draw the production-possibility frontier for countries 1 (green) and 2 (red). When we rotate the diagram of country 2, we end up with an Edgeworth box, which here will help understand how great the gains of international trade are and therefore helps illustrate how trade is not a sum zero game.

Video – Edgeworth box:


Production possibility frontier


The production possibility frontier (PPF) represents the quantity of output that can be obtained for a certain quantity of inputs using a given technology. Depending on the technology, the PPF will have a certain shape.

As you can see on the adjacent figure, this PPF (blue curve) slopes downwards. This slope, which equals the marginal rate of transformation between X and Y, shows us how, in order to increase the output X, the quantity of Y must decrease. In fact, the marginal rate of transformation measures the tradeoff of producing more X in terms of Y.

This frontier determines the maximum output (of both X and Y) that can be obtained given the technology. Production at point A will produce more quantity of Y and less of X than production at point B. However, both are technically efficient, since they maximize the output. For example, production at point C is technically inefficient because, at any point on the PPF, more combined output is produced using given the technology. Also, point D is unattainable given the technology, being this is the reason why it is outside the PPF.

The PPF can be derived from the contract curve on an Edgeworth box. In this box, we see the quantity of inputs (K, L) being used in the production of each good (X,Y). In fact, we can see how, for each quantity of each product, the quantity of each input can change. The isoquants (green curve for X, red for Y) determine how much a certain input has to increase in order to compensate the decrease in the other input, maintaining the quantity of output produced unaltered. The slope of these curves is given by the marginal rate of technical substitution of each output.


The points where the isoquants of different outputs combination intersect, which are Pareto-optimal, allow us to draw the contract curve, from which the PPF can be derived. Since the technology is given, only one PPF can be derived from the contract curve (as opposed to the case of the utility possibility frontier).

 

Video – Production possibility frontier:


General equilibrium


A market system is in competitive equilibrium when prices are set in such a way that the market clears, or in other words, demand and supply are equalised. At this competitive equilibrium, firms’ profits will necessarily have to be zero, because otherwise there will be new firms that, attracted by the profits, would enter the market increasing supply and pushing prices down. Following the first fundamental theorem of welfare economics, this equilibrium must be Pareto efficient. Both will have a fundamental relation as a mechanism for determining optimal production, consumption and exchange.

Initial approach:

Let’s consider an economy where there are:

Two factors of production: capital (K) and labour (L).

Two goods: good X and good Y.

Two agents: A and B

The economic problem that is faced needs to find the most adequate allocation of factors of production in order to produce goods X and Y and how these goods will be distributed amongst consumers A and B. This configuration will be such that there will be no other feasible configuration that will allow an increase in any individual’s welfare without decreasing the other individual’s welfare.

In order to achieve Pareto optimality, a certain set of assumptions need to be held.

-The production function needs to be continuous, differentiable, and strictly concave. This will result in a convex set of production possibilities, also known as production possibility frontier Its shape shows an increasing opportunity cost as we need to use a higher number of resources in order to produce a larger amount of a certain good.

-Consumers’ preferences need to be monotonic, convex and continuous, showing how individuals’ welfare increases with a greater amount of goods, but with a decreasing marginal utility.

Perfect and free availability of information.

-There has to be an absence of externalities and public goods so the utility of individuals depends directly and uniquely from their possession of goods X and Y.

Production optimisation

The optimisation problem in production relies in the maximisation of total output production taking into consideration that it is subject to a limited amount of capital and labour. Analytically,


We can start by looking at the production of goods X and Y as two different optimisation problems. The firm will have to decide what quantity of capital and labour allocate to the production of good X, as shown on the left side of the diagram below, but also what quantity of capital and labour assign to the production of good Y, as shown on the right. These curves are the isoquants corresponding to each production process. 


These two diagrams can be plotted together using what is known as the Edgeworth box, which makes it easier to compare quantities of capital and labour used, while also comparing quantities of goods X and Y being produced. Indeed, it’s not only easier to analyse, but also makes more sense, since the total available quantities of capital and labour are given. 


The solution to this problem is related to the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS). A higher efficiency will be achieved if the reallocation of a unit of labour or capital from one good to another leads to a higher production of the former. When the marginal rate of technical substitution is equal for both goods, it means that all available inputs are being used, which translates into a purely efficient production process. 


Graphically, if we plot all these points we construct what is known as the contract curve (blue curve in the Edgeworth box). These represent all Pareto efficient distributions, such as F, G or H. I is not Pareto efficient, since going from I to either G or H would result in an increase in the production of one of the goods without giving up the production of the other.  From this curve we can derive the production possibility frontier, which shows the quantities of goods X and Y being produced, as shown in the following diagram. It must be noted that both the contract curve and its derivative, the production possibility frontier, show all the solutions that are Pareto efficient from the firm’s point of view. Only when considering input and output prices will we be able to determine a unique solution (because of the concavity of the production possibility frontier).


Consumption optimisation

Bundles of goods cannot be ranked in a reliable way without knowledge of the distribution of the products, especially if a bundle has different amounts of each good. There may be some bundles that have more products of a good but less of another. The optimisation problem will be to maximise the utility of individuals A and B subject to a limited total amount of goods X and Y. Analytically,


In this case we have to achieve the optimal distribution of two, already produced goods (X and Y) between two individuals (A and B). We can follow the same step by step method used before. Here, we’ll plot indifference curves corresponding to the amounts of goods X and Y consumed by A (on the left), and the amounts of goods consumed by B (on the right).


Again, we use the Edgeworth box to graph the different distributions that can be given between two individuals, A and B, and two goods, X and Y. The further the indifference curve is from the origin, the higher the level of utility enjoyed by the consumer. 


Although all the points in the graphic are feasible, not all are efficient, given the utilities and preferences of consumers. The indifference curves join all the points that give consumers the same level of utility. By connecting all points of tangency between the indifference curves of both individuals, the contract curve is constructed and represents all Pareto efficient allocations. The tangency between indifference curves is the point where both consumers have an equal marginal rate of substitution for goods X and Y, and are therefore not willing to trade between them, as it would result in a lower utility.


Global optimum

Until now we have only considered different parts of the economy, and not the economy as a whole. The optimisation problem faced this time is similar to the previous one, although this time an additional restriction is added, since we are here considering both production and consumption: the production level also needs to be efficient. 



As this optimisation problem is based on the previous one, we have the same marginal rate of substitution equalisation, but also these two must be equal to the marginal rate of transformation, the PPF’s slope, 


These solutions are multiple, since there are various points where the condition holds. However, if we consider output prices (given by the consideration of input prices mentioned before), we are able to consider a unique solution. In the adjacent diagram, if output prices were to be PX and PY, the equilibrium would be point E. However, if output prices were instead P’X and P’Y, the equilibrium would be point E’.


Let’s say that prices are set at PX and PY, and that the equilibrium point is E, as seen in the diagram below. Consumers A and B will consume both goods X and Y in different amounts. These amounts are given by the equilibrium in consumption, point E on the contract curve. We have also equilibrium in the production process, given by point E on the production possibility frontier. We know this is a general equilibrium because the marginal rate of substitution is equal to the marginal rate of transformation; or, in other words, the slopes of the indifference curves are equal to the slopes of the production possibility frontier.


Competitive markets result in an equilibrium position such that it is not possible to make a change in the allocation without making someone else worse-off. In reality there are many Pareto optimums and we cannot state that one is better than the other. Even if one consumer got all of the production and the other one none, we cannot say it is an inefficient distribution if all resources are being used efficiently. This is the reason why some economists believe it is an incomplete criterion. However, there are others, such as Milton Friedman and the advocates of the Chicago School, for whom this proves that the economy will act efficiently without the need of government intervention.

Fundamental theorems


There are two fundamental theorems of welfare economics.

 

-First fundamental theorem of welfare economics (also known as the “Invisible Hand Theorem”):

any competitive equilibrium leads to a Pareto efficient allocation of resources.

The main idea here is that markets lead to social optimum. Thus, no intervention of the government is required, and it should adopt only “laissez faire” policies. However, those who support government intervention say that the assumptions needed in order for this theorem to work, are rarely seen in real life.

It must be noted that a situation where someone holds every good and the rest of the population holds none, is a Pareto efficient distribution. However, this situation can hardly be considered as perfect under any welfare definition. The second theorem allows a more reliable definition of welfare

 

-Second fundamental theorem of welfare economics:

any efficient allocation can be attained by a competitive equilibrium, given the market mechanisms leading to redistribution.

This theorem is important because it allows for a separation of efficiency and distribution matters. Those supporting government intervention will ask for wealth redistribution policies.

https://cutt.ly/B7XTS8D