Показаны сообщения с ярлыком cost curve. Показать все сообщения
Показаны сообщения с ярлыком cost curve. Показать все сообщения

четверг, 8 июня 2023 г.

Types of Costs

 A list and definition of different types of economic costs.

Fixed Costs (FC) The costs which don’t vary with changing output. Fixed costs might include the cost of building a factory, insurance and legal bills. Even if your output changes or you don’t produce anything, your fixed costs stay the same. In the above example, fixed costs are always £1,000.

Variable Costs (VC) Costs which depend on the output produced. For example, if you produce more cars, you have to use more raw materials such as metal. This is a variable cost.

Semi-Variable Cost. Labour might be a semi-variable cost. If you produce more cars, you need to employ more workers; this is a variable cost. However, even if you didn’t produce any cars, you may still need some workers to look after an empty factory.

Total Costs (TC)  = Fixed + Variable Costs

Marginal Costs – Marginal cost is the cost of producing an extra unit. If the total cost of 3 units is 1550, and the total cost of 4 units is 1900. The marginal cost of the 4th unit is 350.

Definition of Marginal Cost

Marginal Cost is the cost of producing an extra unit.

It is the addition to Total Cost from selling one extra unit.

QTotal Cost (TC)Marginal Cost (MC)Average Cost (AC)
1101010
21668
32377.6
43298
545139
6662111
  • For example, the marginal cost of producing the fifth unit of output is 13.
  • The total cost of producing five units is 45.
  • But, for the marginal cost, we find, the change in total cost of producing the fifth unit.
    • Total cost of 4 units 32
    • Total cost of 5 units 45
    • Marginal cost of 5th unit = 13

Diagram Showing Marginal Cost


Note:  Marginal cost is often shaped like this in the short term because of the law of diminishing marginal returns.

Opportunity Cost – Opportunity cost is the next best alternative foregone. If you invest £1million in developing a cure for pancreatic cancer, the opportunity cost is that you can’t use that money to invest in developing a cure for skin cancer.

Economic Cost. Economic cost includes both the actual direct costs (accounting costs) plus the opportunity cost. For example, if you take time off work to a training scheme. You may lose a weeks pay of £350, plus also have to pay the direct cost of £200. Thus the total economic cost = £550.

Accounting Costs – this is the monetary outlay for producing a certain good. Accounting costs will include your variable and fixed costs you have to pay.

Sunk Costs. These are costs that have been incurred and cannot be recouped. If you left the industry, you could not reclaim sunk costs. For example, if you spend money on advertising to enter an industry, you can never claim these costs back. If you buy a machine, you might be able to sell if you leave the industry. See: Sunk cost fallacy

Avoidable Costs. Costs that can be avoided. If you stop producing cars, you don’t have to pay for extra raw materials and electricity. Sometimes known as an escapable cost.

Explicit costs – these are costs that a firm directly pays for and can be seen on the accounting sheet. Explicit costs can be variable or fixed, just a clear amount.

Implicit costs – these are opportunity costs, which do not necessarily appear on its balance sheet but affect the firm. For example, if a firm used its assets, like a printing press to print leaflets for a charity, it means that it loses out on revenue from producing commercial leaflets.

Absorbed costs

Absorbed costs involve including all the variable and fixed costs in producing a unit of output.

For example, in producing a motor car, the absorbed costs include the variable raw material costs and the associated fixed manufacturing costs, such as the factory, safety inspections and maintenance of machines.

Absorbed costs would not include general administration of a firm or expenditure on advertising.

Absorbed vs variable costs

Absorbed costs can be contrasted with the variable costs or the direct costs of producing a good. The direct costs are those specific to the good – labour, raw materials. However, this excludes those fixed costs which are part of the overall cost.


Which is better to use absorbed costs or variable costs?

For certain decisions, firms may prefer to use variable costs. Variable costs give a guide to operating profit – given that fixed costs have already been spent. For short-term decision making, a firm will look at marginal cost (which will be the extra variable costs associated with increasing output) and marginal revenue.

For external accounting and evaluation in the long-term, absorption costs are needed. They give a fuller picture of the long-term profitability of the firm and real costs associated with producing a good.

Evaluation of absorbed costs

  • One issue with absorbed costs is deciding what will count as a fixed manufacturing overhead cost.
  • The cost per unit will typically fall with increased output. Economies of scale will reduce the manufacturing average fixed costs.

Isoquant and isocosts

  • An isoquant shows all combination of factors that produce a certain output
  • An isocost show all combinations of factors that cost the same amount.
  • Isocosts and isoquants can show the optimal combination of factors of production to produce the maximum output at minimum cost.

Definition isoquant

An isoquant shows all the combination of two factors that produce a given output

In this diagram, the isoquant shows all the combinations of labour and capital that can produce a total output (Total Physical Product TPP) of 4,000. In the above isoquant, this could be

  • 20 capital and 18 labour or (more capital intensive)
  • 9 capital and 35 labour. (more labour intensive

An isoquant is usually shaped convex to the origin because of the law of Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS) which means there are diminishing returns from using more of one factor of production.

Marginal rate of factor substitution



The marginal rate of substitution is the amount of one factor (e.g. K) that can be replaced by one factor (e.g. L). If 2 units of capital could be replaced with one-factor labour, the MRS would be 2


Diminishing marginal rate of substitution

If the firm employs 2 L and 40 K. Then employing one extra worker can enable it to save 10K. This is quite an efficient saving. The firm only has to pay one extra worker but can save the cost of 40.

However, at a combination of 9 Labour, employing an extra worker enables a saving of only 2 capital. Therefore, the more that workers are employed, there is diminishing rate at which you can substitute the other factor. There comes a point, where employing more workers barely saves any capital at all. This is when diminishing returns of labour is very high – workers effectively get in each other’s way.

As one moves down the isoquant, output remains the same. Therefore the output gained from employing more labour must equal the output lost from employing more capital.

MPP (L) x ΔL = MPP (K) x ΔK

This equation gives us


Isoquant map

An isoquant map shows different levels of output. For example

  • I1 may show the combinations of capital and labour that can produce 4,000 TPP.
  • I2 may show the combinations of capital and labour that can produce 5,000 TPP.
  • I5 is a higher output than I4

In the short-term, a firm faces a trade-off along one particular isoquant. But, in the long-term, a firm can invest in increasing capital stock and produce at a higher output for the same quantity of labour.

Isocost

An isocost shows all the combinations of factors that cost the same to employ.

In this example, a unit of labour and capital cost £6,666 each.

  • If we employ 30K and 30L, the total cost will be £200,000 + £200,000
  • If we employ 10 K and 50L, the total cost will be £66,666 +£333,333 = £400,000

Change in labour costs


  • In this example, initially, the cost of labour and capital is both £5,000. (e.g. 60L = 60 x £5,000 = £300,000)
  • However, if Labour cost rises to £10,000, then the isocost shifts to the left. Now, to keep cost at £300,000, a firm could only employ 30 workers (30 x £10,000)
  • The slope of an isocost is, therefore, Pι / Pκ

Profit maximisation

To maximise profits, a firm will wish to produce at the point of the highest possible isoquant and minimum possible isocost

In this example, we have one isocost and three isoquants. With the isocost of £400,000 the maximum output a firm can manage would be a TPP of 4,000. If it produced at say 13 K and 48 Labour, it would only be able to produce a TPP of 3,500.

A total TPP of 4,500 is currently not possible without increasing costs beyond £400,000

Profit maximisation – the least cost method of production


Another way of seeking to maximise profits is to target an output of say 4,00 and then find the isocost with the lowest possible cost. In this case, the isocost which touches the tangential point of the TPP is a TC of £400,000.

Market Failure

  • Social Costs. This is the total cost to society. It will include the private costs plus also the external cost (cost incurred by a third party). May also be referred to as ‘True costs’

Social Cost

Definition of social cost – Social cost is the total cost to society. It includes private costs plus any external costs.

Example of driving to work


  • Costs of paying for petrol (personal cost)
  • Costs of increased congestion (external cost)
  • Pollution and worse air quality (external cost)
  • The social cost includes all the above. (Petrol + congestion + pollution)

Example of social cost – smoking

If you smoke, the private cost is £6 for a packet of 20 cigarettes. But, there are also external costs to society

  • Air pollution and risks of passive smoking
  • Litter from discarded cigarette butts
  • Health costs to society

The social costs of smoking include the total of all private and external costs.

Example of social cost of building airport

Private costs of airport

  • Cost of constructing an airport.
  • Cost of paying workers to run airport

External costs of airport

  • Noise and air pollution to those living nearby.
  • Risk of an accident to those living nearby.
  • Loss of landscape.

Importance of social cost

Rational choice theory suggests individuals will only consider their private costs. For example, if deciding how to travel, we will consider the cost of petrol and time taken to drive. However, we won’t take into consideration the impact on the environment or congestion levels for other members in society.

Therefore, if social costs significantly vary from private costs then we may get a socially inefficient outcome in a free market.

Marginal social cost (MSC)

The marginal social cost is the cost to society of producing/consuming one extra unit of output.

Example of Marginal social cost


  • PMC = Private marginal cost
  • XMC = External marginal cost
  • SMC = Social marginal cost

Diagram showing marginal social costs


For goods with negative externalities the social cost is greater than the private cost.

In a free market, if people ignore the external costs, the equilibrium will be at output 20. But, social efficiency (where social marginal cost = social marginal benefit) would be at output 16.

  • External Costs. This is the cost imposed on a third party. For example, if you smoke, some people may suffer from passive smoking. That is the external cost.
  • Private Costs. The costs you pay. e.g. the private cost of a packet of cigarettes is £6.10
  • Social Marginal Cost. The total cost to society of producing one extra unit. Social Marginal Cost (SMC) = Private marginal cost (PMC) + External marginal Cost (XMC)

Diagram of Costs Curves

  • Total Fixed Cost (TFC) – costs independent of output, e.g. paying for factory
  • Marginal cost (MC) – the cost of producing an extra unit of output.
  • Total variable cost (TVC) = cost involved in producing more units, which in this case is the cost of employing workers.
  • Average Variable Cost AVC = Total variable cost / quantity produced
  • Total cost TC = Total variable cost (VC) + total fixed cost (FC)
  • Average Total Cost ATC = Total cost / quantity

Costs in the short run

Short run cost curves tend to be U shaped because of diminishing returns.

In the short run, capital is fixed. After a certain point, increasing extra workers leads to declining productivity. Therefore, as you employ more workers the marginal cost increases.

Diagram of Marginal Cost 


Because the short run marginal cost curve is sloped like this, mathematically the average cost curve will be U shaped. Initially, average costs fall. But, when marginal cost is above the average cost, then average cost starts to rise.

Marginal cost always passes through the lowest point of the average cost curve.

Average Cost Curves


  • ATC (Average Total Cost) = Total Cost / quantity
  • AVC (Average Variable Cost) = Variable cost / Quantity
  • AFC (Average Fixed Cost) = Fixed cost / Quantity

Costs


  • Fixed costs (FC)  remain constant. Therefore the more you produce, the lower the average fixed costs will be.
  • To work out the marginal cost, you just see how much TC has increased by.
  • For example, the third unit sees TC increase from 450 to 500, therefore, the increase in MC is 50.
  • The 12th unit sees total cost rise from 1,700 to 2,400, so the marginal cost is 700

Average fixed costs


Fixed, variable and total cost curves


Total cost (TC) = Variable cost (VC) + fixed costs (FC)

Long Run Cost Curves

The long-run cost curves are u shaped for different reasons. It is due to economies of scale and diseconomies of scale. If a firm has high fixed costs, increasing output will lead to lower average costs.


However, after a certain output, a firm may experience diseconomies of scale. This occurs where increased output leads to higher average costs. For example, in a big firm, it is more difficult to communicate and coordinate workers.

Diagram for Economies and Diseconomies of Scale 


Note, however, not all firms will experience diseconomies of scale. It is possible the LRAC could just be downward sloping.




https://www.economicshelp.org/

суббота, 4 февраля 2023 г.

Module 8: Cost Curves

 THE POLICY QUESTION

SHOULD THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT PROMOTE THE DOMESTIC PRODUCTION OF STREETCARS?

In recent years, streetcars have enjoyed a bit of a renaissance in the United States. Streetcars are electric-powered public vehicles that ride on rails embedded into normal city streets and comingle with traffic. Once common in the United States and still common in many European cities, streetcars all but disappeared from US streets in the second half of the twentieth century. Portland, Oregon, is one city that revived the streetcar and subsequently expanded its system.

After initially buying streetcars from the German company Siemens, Portland’s transit authority and government, pushed by the federal government, which funds a large portion of urban transit projects, decided to contract with a local firm, Oregon Iron Works, to produce the streetcars locally. Oregon Iron Works had no experience in manufacturing streetcars but created a subsidiary firm to do so called United Streetcar. Other US cities that were introducing streetcars, such as Washington, DC, and Tucson, Arizona, contracted with Oregon Iron Works for their cars as well. In the end, the firm faced severe delays and cost overruns and eventually got very behind on its scheduled delivery. In addition, the expected boom in streetcars slowed considerably with the recession of 2008 and changing municipal priorities. In 2014, United Streetcar ceased production and laid off its workers.

EXPLORING THE POLICY QUESTION

Is the story of United Streetcar an example of a misguided effort to steer business domestically? Would it have succeeded if the market for streetcars in the United States had not dried up? To answer these questions, we need to think about the cost structure of the industry and whether there are aspects of it that would support the decision to start manufacturing streetcars domestically. Cost curves—the subject of this chapter—are critical tools for analyzing a company’s cost structure.

LEARNING OBJECTIVES

8.1 Short-Run Cost Curves

Learning Objective 8.1: Derive the seven short-run cost curves from the total cost function.

8.2 Long-Run Cost Curves

Learning Objective 8.2: Derive the three long-run cost curves from the total cost function.

8.3 Short-Run versus Long-Run Costs: The Advantage of Flexibility

Learning Objective 8.3: Explain why long-run costs are always as low as or lower than short-run costs and how more flexibility in choosing inputs is always better than less.

8.4 Multiproduct Firms, Learning Curves, and Learning by Doing

Learning Objective 8.4: Explain how making more than one product, learning over time, and learning by producing can lower costs.

8.5 Policy Example
Should the Federal Government Promote Domestic Production of Streetcars?

Learning Objective 8.5: Use a cost analysis to explain why building streetcars domestically in the United States is or is not a good policy.

8.1 SHORT-RUN COST CURVES

Learning Objective 8.1: Derive the seven short-run cost curves from the total cost function.

A cost curve represents the relationship between output and the different cost measures involved in producing the output. Cost curves are visual descriptions of the various costs of production. In order to maximize profits, firms need to know how costs vary with output, so cost curves are vital to the profit maximization decisions of firms.

There are two categories of cost curves: short run and long run. In this section, we focus on short-run cost curves.

The Seven Short-Run Cost Measures

The short run, as we learned in the previous chapter, is a time period short enough that some inputs are fixed while others are variable. There are seven cost curves in the short run: fixed cost, variable cost, total cost, average fixed cost, average variable cost, average total cost, and marginal cost.

The fixed cost () of production is the cost of production that does not vary with output level. The fixed cost is the cost of the fixed inputs in production, such as the cost of a machine (capital) that costs the same to operate no matter how much production is happening. An example of such a machine is a conveyor belt in a factory that moves a streetcar chassis through various stages of an assembly line. The belt is either on or off, but the cost of running it does not change depending on how many streetcars it carries at any point in time.

Note that the fixed cost of a piece of capital equipment that the company owns includes the opportunity cost as well. In our example, the fixed cost includes the actual costs of running the conveyer belt, such as power and maintenance, as well as the opportunity cost of using it for the firm’s own production rather than renting it out to another company.

The variable cost () of production is the cost of production that varies with output level. This is the cost of the variable inputs in production—for example, the cost of the workers that assemble the electronic devices along a conveyor belt. The number of workers might depend on how many devices the factory is trying to produce in a day. If its production target increases, it uses more labor. Thus the hourly wages it pays for these workers are a variable cost. Variable cost generally increases with the amount of output produced.

Like fixed cost of production, there is an opportunity cost associated with variable cost of production. In this case, the next best use of these workers is to go to another firm that will employ them. Thus the market wage for workers represents their opportunity cost, and as such, the wage cost of employing them is equivalent to their opportunity cost.

The total cost () of production is the sum of fixed and variable costs of production:

=+

There are three short-run average cost measures: average variable cost, average fixed cost, and average total cost.

Average variable cost () is the variable cost per unit of output. Mathematically, it is simply the variable cost divided by the output:

=/

Note that since variable cost generally increases with the amount of output produced, the average variable cost can increase or decrease as output increases.

Average fixed cost () is the fixed cost per unit of output. Mathematically, it is simply the fixed cost divided by the output:

=/

Because fixed cost does not change with the amount of output produced, the average fixed cost always decreases as output increases.

Average total cost (), or simply average cost, of production is total cost per unit of output. This is the same as the sum of the average fixed cost and the average variable cost:

=/=+

Because it is the sum of the average fixed cost, which is always declining with output, and the average variable cost, which may increase or decrease with output, the average total cost may increase or decrease with output.

Marginal cost () is the additional cost incurred from the production of one more unit of output. Thus marginal cost is

=ΔΔ.

The only part of total cost that increases with an additional unit of output is the variable cost, so we can re-write the marginal cost as

=ΔΔ.

Calculus

The marginal cost is the rate of change of the total cost as output increases, or the slope of the total cost function, (). To find this, we need to simply take the derivative of the total cost function:

()=()

Since ()=+(), we can rewrite this derivative as ()=+().

 is a constant, so =0. Thus ()=().

Since fixed cost does not change as output increases, marginal cost depends only on the variable cost.

ixed Cost, Variable Cost, and Total Cost Curves

Table 8.1.1 summarizes a firm’s daily short-run costs. The firm has a fixed cost of $50 per day of production. This cost is incurred whether the firm produces or not, as we can see by the fact that $50 is still a cost when output is zero. The firm’s fixed cost of $50 does not change with the amount of output produced. The data in the first two columns of table 8.1.1 allow us to draw the firm’s fixed cost curve. It is a horizontal line at $50, as shown in figure 8.1.1.

Table 8.1.1 An example of the seven short-run cost measures, organized by total cost per unit of output.
Output (variable Q)Fixed cost (variable FC)Variable cost (variable VC)Total cost (variable C)Marginal cost (variable MC)Average fixed cost (variable AFC)Average variable cost (variable AVC)Average cost (variable AC)
When Output(Q) equals 0…FC=50VC=0C=50MC=0AFC=0AVC=0AC=0
When Output(Q) equals 1…FC=50VC=40C=90MC=40AFC=50.0AVC=40.0AC=90.0
When Output(Q) equals 2…FC=50VC=70C=120MC=30AFC=25.0AVC=35.0AC=60.0
When Output(Q) equals 3…FC=50VC=90C=140MC=20AFC=16.7AVC=30.0AC=46.7
When Output(Q) equals 4…FC=50VC=100C=150MC=10AFC=12.5AVC=25.0AC=37.5
When Output(Q) equals 5…FC=50VC=120C=170MC=20AFC=10.0AVC=24.0AC=34.0
When Output(Q) equals 6…FC=50VC=150C=200MC=30AFC=8.3AVC=25.0AC=33.3
When Output(Q) equals 7…FC=50VC=190C=240MC=40AFC=7.1AVC=27.1AC=34.3
When Output(Q) equals 8…FC=50VC=240C=290MC=50AFC=6.3AVC=30.0AC=36.3
When Output(Q) equals 9…FC=50VC=300C=350MC=60AFC=5.6AVC=33.3AC=38.9
When Output(Q) equals 10…FC=50VC=370C=420MC=70AFC=5.0AVC=37.0AC=42.0
Figure 8.1.1 Three short-run cost curves: fixed, variable, and total costs

Figure 8.1.1 also shows variable and total cost curves plotted from data in table 8.1.1. The variable cost increases with output because extra output requires extra variable inputs. As we can see in the graph, the variable cost curve rises as output, , increases.

The short-run variable cost curve is determined by and matches the shape of the short-run production function, which we studied in chapter 6. The short-run production function is the same as the total product of labor curve when labor is the variable input in the short run, which we always assume it is. To go from the production function to the variable cost curve requires knowing the price of labor. Let’s assume a constant price of labor, say $10 an hour.

Figure 8.1.2 presents a typical short-run production function, which leads to the shape of the variable cost curve in figure 8.1.1. The production function exhibits increasing marginal returns to labor initially: as the labor input is increased from zero, the output increases at an increasing rate. Eventually, however, the addition of extra hours of labor leads to additional output at a decreasing rate. This happens as we increase labor input from ten hours of labor.


Figure 8.1.2 The total product of labor curve

If we multiply the amount of labor at every level of output in figure 8.1.2 by the wage rate of $10 per hour, we get the variable cost curve from figure 8.1.1.

Marginal, Average Fixed, Average Variable, and Average Total Cost Curves

Figure 8.1.3 presents the four remaining short-run cost curves: marginal cost (), average fixed cost (), average variable cost (), and average total cost ().

Figure 8.1.3 Short-run marginal cost, average fixed cost, average variable cost, and average total cost curves

The marginal cost, average variable cost, and average total cost curves are derived from the total cost curve.

From figure 8.1.3, we can see that the marginal cost curve crosses both the average variable cost curve and the average fixed cost curve at their minimum points. This is not random. Since the marginal cost indicates the extra cost incurred from the production of the next unit of output, if this cost is lower than the average, it must be bringing the average down. If this cost is higher than the average, it must pull the average up. Think of your own grade point average: if your average this term is higher than your overall average, your overall average will go up. If your average this term is lower than your overall average, your overall average will go down.

Calculus

  1. If the total cost curve of a firm is ()=25+102 
    1. What is the marginal cost curve?
    2. What is marginal cost at =125?

8.2 LONG-RUN COST CURVES

Learning Objective 8.2: Derive the three long-run cost curves from the total cost function.

As we learned in previous chapters, in the long run, all inputs are variable, and there are no fixed costs. In this section, we look at the three long-run cost curves—total cost, average cost, and marginal cost—and how to derive them.

Long-Run Total Cost Curve

To determine the long-run total cost (LRTC) for a firm, we must think about the cost minimization problem introduced in chapter 7. Remember that the cost minimization problem answers the question, What is the most cost-effective way to produce a given amount of output? The total cost curve represents the cost associated with every possible level of output, so if we figure out the cost-minimizing choice of inputs for every possible level of output, we can determine the cost of producing each level of output.

When we do this exercise, we are looking for the expansion path of the firm. Recall from chapter 7 that the expansion path is the combination of inputs that minimize costs for every level of output, and it can be graphed as a curve. Figure 8.2.1 shows the expansion path for a firm that manufactures tablet computers.

Figure 8.2.1 Expansion path

Each point on the expansion path is the solution to the cost minimization problem for that particular output. Recall from chapter 7 that  is the rental rate or price of capital and  is the wage rate or price of labor. Consider point X: here the output quantity is set at ten million, and the tangency of the isocost and isoquant at this point establishes the optimal combination of the inputs. To go from this point to the cost, we have only to know the combined cost of the inputs. Fortunately, the isocost line tells us exactly that; the total cost here is 1. Now consider point Y, where the output quantity has increased to twenty million. With this, the new production level is associated with a new isocost curve, with total cost at 2. Finally, point Z indicates that for an output quantity of thirty million, the total cost is 3.

From the expansion path, we can draw the total cost curve. We have three points already, X, Y, and Z. Point X describes a quantity of ten million tablets and a total cost of 1. Point Y describes a quantity of twenty million tablets and a total cost of 2. Point Z describes a quantity of thirty million tablets and a total cost of 3. These three cost-quantity pairs are three points on the long-run total cost curve illustrated in figure 8.2.2.


Figure 8.2.2 The long-run total cost curve

Remember from chapter 7 that the total cost is the sum of the input costs, =+. As we expand output, we must use more inputs, and the increase in labor and capital results in increasing overall cost of production.

A firm’s long-run average cost (LRAC) is the cost per unit of output. In other words, it is the total cost, LRTC, divided by output, :

()=()

A firm’s long-run marginal cost (LRMC) is the increase in total cost from an increase in an additional unit of output:

()=Δ()Δ

where Δ() is the change in total cost and Δ is the change in output. This is the same thing as the slope of the total cost curve, ().

Calculus

The long-run marginal cost is the rate of change of the total cost as output increases, or the slope of the total cost function, (). To find this, we need to simply take the derivative of the total cost function:

trates the relationship between the total cost curve (panel a) and erage and marginal cost curves (panel b).

Figure 8.2.3 Deriving long-run average and marginal cost curves from the long-run total cost curve

To see how long-run total and average costs are related, take point A on the total cost curve in figure 8.2.3. At this point, we can derive the average cost by dividing the vertical distance, which gives us the total cost, by the horizontal distance, which gives us quantity. This is the same thing as the slope of the ray from the origin that connects to point A: it is the “rise” over the “run.” So in panel b, we have the same quantity on the horizontal axis but the slope of the ray connecting to point A, or the average cost, on the vertical axis. Point A is, therefore, a point on the average cost curve. Note that as we move out along the total cost curve, the ray from the origin to the total cost curve becomes less and less steep until point B, after which the slope gets steeper. Thus point B is the point of minimum average cost, as illustrated in panel b.

To understand the relationship between long-run total cost and marginal cost, let’s go back to point A in panel a. The marginal cost is the same as the slope of the total cost curve, and we can illustrate the slope by using a tangent line: a straight line that passes through point A and has the same slope as the curve at that point. This slope gives us the marginal cost. Note that this slope is not as steep as the ray from the origin that defined average cost at this point. Therefore, in panel b, the marginal cost is lower than the average. We can also observe that as we move along the total cost curve, the slope continues to decrease until point C, after which the slope begins to increase. Thus point C is the minimum marginal cost, as illustrated on the marginal cost curve in panel b.

Finally, note that at point B on the total cost curve, the slope of the ray from the origin and the slope of the total cost curve are identical. At this point, the marginal and the average costs are the same, as seen by the intersection of the two curves in panel b.

This relationship between average and marginal costs is not a coincidence; it is always true. When average cost is above marginal cost, average cost must be decreasing. When average cost is lower than marginal cost, average cost must be increasing. And when average and marginal costs are equal, average cost is not changing. This relationship is described in table 8.2.1 and illustrated in figure 8.2.4.

Table 8.2.1 The relationship between long-run average and marginal costs
Relationship between AC and MCResulting change in AC
()<()() increasing
()>()() decreasing
()=()() constant
Figure 8.2.4 Relationship between the long-run average and marginal cost curves

On the left half of figure 8.2.4, the average cost is above the marginal cost, and thus the average cost is falling. In the right half of figure 8.2.4, the average cost is below the marginal cost, and thus the average cost is rising. At the intersection of the two curves, the average cost is at its minimum, and the slope of the average cost curve is zero.

Economies and Diseconomies of Scale

An important economic concept associated with the long-run average cost curve is economies of scale. Economies of scale occur when the average cost of production falls as output increases. Similarly, diseconomies of scale occur when the average cost of production rises as output increases. In a typical long-run average cost curve, there are sections of both economies of scale and diseconomies of scale. There is also a point or region of minimum efficient scale where average cost is at its minimum. This is the point where economies of scale are used up and no longer benefit the firm. Figure 8.2.5 illustrates these points.

Figure 8.2.5 Economies, diseconomies, and minimum efficient scale

8.3 SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN COSTS: THE ADVANTAGE OF FLEXIBILITY

Learning Objective 8.3: Explain why long-run costs are always as low as or lower than short-run costs and how more flexibility in choosing inputs is always better than less.

Short-run average costs are constrained by the presence of a fixed input. So in the long run, we can always do at least as well as, and often better than, what we do in the short run with respect to cost. We can see this is true by comparing the long-run and short-run average cost curves.

The long-run average cost curve is a type of lower boundary of the short-run cost curves. This can be understood most easily by thinking of a series of short-run average total cost curves, each one for a different level of the fixed input, capital, as shown in figure 8.3.1.


Figure 8.3.1 The long-run average cost curve as the lower boundary of short-run average cost curves

Since capital is variable in the long run, the long-run average cost is essentially the same as picking among the short-run average total cost curves and combining the capital with the optimal level of labor, or in other words, the minimum ATC.

The long-run average cost curve illustrates the benefit of flexibility: by being able to choose both inputs, the firm can ensure that the efficient mix of the inputs is being used at all times, which keeps costs at their minimum points for all output levels. This flexibility means that we can expect that in the long run, the average cost of production is at least as low as, and generally lower than, what it is in the short run.

8.4 MULTIPRODUCT FIRMS, LEARNING CURVES, AND LEARNING BY DOING

Learning Objective 8.4: Explain how making more than one product, learning over time, and learning by producing can lower costs.

A number of other factors matter in a firm’s ability to lower costs. In this section, we look at two of them.

Multiproduct Firms

Often, a firm will make more than one product. This raises the interesting question, When is it better for the same firm to make multiple products than for multiple firms to each make one product? One answer lies in the concept of economies of scope: an economy of scope exists when the average cost of one product falls as the production of another product increases.

Take, for example, a firm that makes large LCD televisions. One expensive component of these displays is the flat glass panels needed for the screen. To make these large screens, very large pieces of glass are manufactured and then cut into individual rectangular pieces for the televisions. Often there are smaller glass pieces left over. Rather than discard these pieces, the same company can make smaller LCD displays for computers, cars, appliances, and so on. Since a lot of the other materials, technical know-how, skilled labor, and the like can be shared across the two types of products, the average cost of both declines when the production of smaller LCD displays for computers is increased.

More formally, we can think of a multiproduct firm as having a cost function that depends on the output of two goods: 1 and 2. Such a cost function can be expressed as (1,+2). We say the economies of scope are present if

(1,2)<(1,0)+(0,2).

This equation makes intuitive sense. The left-hand side of the inequality is the cost of a single firm that produced positive quantities of both goods. The right-hand side is the total cost of producing only 1 added to the total cost of producing only 2. If it is cheaper to produce the two together, then the inequality holds.

Learning Curves

Sometimes firms get better at making things over time, as they gain experience. Economists call this learning by doing. Learning by doing means that as the cumulative output—the total output ever produced—of the firm increases, the average cost falls.

Learning by doing can take different forms:

  • Over time, workers become more efficient at specific tasks they perform repeatedly.
  • Managers can observe production and adjust task assignments and other aspects of the production process.
  • Engineers can optimize product and plant design to increase efficiency.
  • Firms can get better at handling inputs, materials, and inventories.

These and other instances of learning by doing often lower firms’ average costs and make them more efficient over time.

The idea of learning by doing can be graphed as a learning curve (figure 8.4.1) where average cost is plotted as a function of either time or cumulative output. The learning curve is different from the typical average cost curve, which represents the total cost divided by current output.

Figure 8.4.1 The learning curve

This temporal view of average costs makes firms’ decisions about operating and investing in the business more complicated. If a firm that is considering shutting down in the face of negative economic profits expects that it will be able to produce more efficiently in the future, it might be willing to accept near-term losses in the expectation of future profits.

The learning curve is potentially important in the policy question. If there is substantial learning involved in the production of a streetcar, then the domestic manufacturer of streetcars might see its production costs decrease significantly as they produce more and more streetcars. So although the short-run costs of production might suggest that domestic promotion is a bad idea, if there is good reason to believe that in the long run, average costs will decrease significantly, a reasonable case could be made for such promotion.

8.5 POLICY EXAMPLE
SHOULD THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT PROMOTE DOMESTIC PRODUCTION OF STREETCARS?

Learning Objective 8.5: Use a cost analysis to explain why building streetcars domestically in the United States is or is not a good policy.

To understand the business of building streetcars, we must first think about the cost structure. Streetcars are large, heavy, and loaded with specific and sophisticated technology, such as electric propulsion engines, car electronics and controls, and passenger controls. Their manufacture takes a factory of considerable size, and yet they are produced in small quantities. This suggests a few things about their costs:

  • There are very large fixed costs because of the machinery and the plant required for constructing these cars. Because of this, the minimum efficient scale is probably far beyond any one manufacturer’s current scale. What this means is that the more streetcars a manufacturer produces, the lower the cost per car.
  • Because of the complexity, there are likely to be large cost savings over time as a result of learning by doing.
  • The complexity of the streetcar itself suggests that the quality of the product from new firms might suffer because they have not had the experience that longtime suppliers have had.

These observations suggest that current suppliers of streetcars, like Siemens, have considerable cost advantages over new firms because of their current production level, which allows them to take advantage of economies of scale, and because they are much farther along the learning curve (see figures 8.5.1 and 8.5.2). Any new firm likely would take a very long time to reach the current manufacturer’s scale efficiencies and cost efficiencies from learning by doing. However, if the demand for streetcars was expected to grow and be sustained for a long period of time, a reasonable case could be made that the domestic industry could mature into a reliable and cost-efficient supplier of streetcars to the United States and even the international market.

Figure 8.5.1 Streetcar manufacturers on the long-run average cost curve

Figure 8.5.2 Streetcar manufacturers on the learning curve

Unfortunately, the projections of the level of demand for streetcars appear to have been far too optimistic. It seems unlikely that the domestic streetcar industry will have a chance to grow and learn, so we may never know if it would have become cost competitive over time.

EXPLORING THE POLICY QUESTION

  1. Because of their size and weight, shipping streetcars internationally is costly. How would you include transportation costs in your analysis of the policy question?
  2. If the market had not dried up, do you think United Streetcar would have succeeded in the long run? Why or why not? Use economic reasoning in your answer.

LEARN: KEY TOPICS

Terms

Fixed cost
Variable cost
Total cost
Average fixed cost
Average variable cost
Average total cost
Marginal cost
Long-run total cost
Long-run average cost
Long-run marginal cost
Expansion path
Economies of scale
Diseconomies of scale
Minimum efficient scale
Economies of scope
Learning by doing
Learning curve

Graphs

Three short-run cost curves: fixed, variable, and total costs
The total product of labor curve
Marginal cost, average fixed cost, average variable cost, and average total cost
Expansion path
The long-run total cost curve
Deriving long-run average and marginal costs curves from the long-run total cost curve
Relationship between the long-run average and marginal cost curves
The long-run average cost curve as the lower boundary of short-run average cost curves
The learning curve

Equations

Short Run Cost Equations

Fixed Cost

Lacks an exact equation: the fixed cost in the context of short-run curves is the cost even when the output is at zero.

Variable cost

Variable cost varies with output level. Variable costs generally increase with the amount of output produced.

Total cost

The sum of fixed and variable costs of production.

=+

Average fixed cost

The fixed cost per unit of output.

=/

Average variable cost

The variable cost per unit of output.

=/

Average total cost

The total cost per unit of output. The sum of the average fixed cost and average variable cost

=/=+

Marginal cost

The additional cost incurred from the production of one more unit of output.

=ΔΔ

Because the only part of total cost that increases with an additional unit of output is the variable cost, we can re-write the marginal cost as

=ΔΔ

Long-run Cost Equations
Long-run cost minimization problem, review.

Long-run Total Cost

The sum of the all input costs

=+

Long-run average cost (LRAC)

The cost per unit of output. Because there is no fixedcost in the Long-run, it is the total cost , divdied by output .

()=()

Long-run marginal cost

The increase in total cost from an increase in an additional unit of output.


https://cutt.ly/d99HRfQ